Abstract:
This dissertation is less about the French Revolution than about using the French Revolutionto improve our understanding of institutional change. Between 1789 and 1815, France went from
absolute monarchy to constitutional monarchy, from constitutional monarchy to Republicanism
and from Republicanism to a de facto military dictatorship which in turn led to the proclamation
of the first Empire. In other words, France from 1789 to 1815 became a genuine laboratory
experiment for studying comparative institutional analysis. Each of the topics covered in this dissertation have in common that they analyze how thegovernment and its agents raise resources, whether it be through price controls, conscription,
inflation or the creation of a central bank, for the benefit of some segments of the population.
Each chapter analyzes through the lenses of Public Choice theory changes which were key to
the development of the French centralized administrative state. Chapter one tries to come up with a theory for why widespread price controls were adoptedin Revolutionary France between 1793 and 1794 despite their cost. I argue that price controls
can be a tool for governments to mobilize additional resources while buying the support of
certain key interest groups, hence making war politically viable. I argue that urban capitalists
benefited from price controls on agricultural output combined with forced sales. I estimate that
in the six months preceding the abolition of price controls, the government saved, by using
them (and in real terms), the equivalent of roughly 40% of the annual 1790 central government
budget. Consistent with the theory expounded in this chapter, once the exigencies of the war
attenuated and as collective action became more costly for the urban population, price controls
were abandoned. Between 1794 and 1796, France experienced an unprecedented hyperinflation fueled by anexplosion of paper money called the assignat. Chapter two (co-authored with Bryan Cutsinger
and Joshua Ingber) uses the assignat hyperinflation as an experiment to illustrate Brennan &
Buchanan (1980)’s view that the presence of a “stable” money demand function depends on
the constitutional rules underlying the money creation process. In September 1795, the French
adopted the Constitution of Year III, which we use to demonstrate how constitutional changes
can have important effects on monetary phenomena. We find that the new regime had a structural
effect on the demand for money that substantially weakened the link between real money
balances and inflation, and that failing to account for this effect results in substantially different
estimates of the seigniorage-maximizing rates of inflation. We also and that the new regime
increased the volatility of inflation, suggesting that the previous regime was more effective at
anchoring the public’s inflation expectations. Taken together, these results lend credence to the
constitutional perspective’s primary theoretical insight. The third chapter discusses the content of my paper “The interest group origins of theBank of France” (published in Public Choice). This paper contrasts different interpretations of
the creation of the Bank of France. I argue that the Bank of France was the product of rent seeking
behavior rather than the pursuit of public interest, as is commonly supposed. I explain
how the changing institutional constraints faced by both politicians and bankers can account
for changes in France’s monetary constitution. The creation of the Bank in 1800 followed
the fall of the Directory and the establishment of Napoléon’s autocratic regime. I argue that
as parliamentarism and the separation of powers were weakened by Napoléon, the cost of
establishing and maintaining a monopoly privilege in banking evaporated and the creation of
the Bank of France became more likely. The fourth and final paper, co-authored with Ennio Piano provides a simple economicframework of how the threat of desertion induces both short-run and long-run institutional
changes. We show that in the short-run, Napoléon’s regime adopted a strategy of discriminatory
conscription enforcement: The French government set a lower (higher) conscription rate for
those regions where, due to their geographic characteristics, the enforcement of conscription
was more (less) costly. In the longer run, Paris centralized the administration of conscription,
employed the army for its domestic enforcement, and introduced a set draconian measures to
punish deserters, their families, and their communities. These actions resulted in a rapid fall
in desertion rates across France, until Napoléon’s failed invasion of Russia compromised the
stability of the regime.